Gregory Mankiw,
NYT: Why Economists Are Worried About International Trade. After analyzing the data, Mr. Frankel and Mr. Romer
concluded that “a rise of one percentage point in the ratio of trade to G.D.P.
increases income per person by at least one-half percent.” In other words,
nations should take the theories of Smith, Ricardo and Melitz seriously. To be sure, expanding trade
hurts some people in the short run, especially those in import-competing
sectors who have to find new jobs. That fact may call for a robust safety net
and effective retraining. But it does not undermine the conclusion that free
trade raises average living standards. That is the theory and evidence
regarding international trade. I don’t expect this academic work to persuade
Mr. Trump. But he is said to pay more attention to briefings that
contain his own name. So let’s return to Adam Smith’s birthplace and ponder
these questions: Should we impose a tariff on Americans vacationing at
Scotland’s Trump International Golf Links? Or should vacationers make their consumption
choices free from the heavy hand of government?
Menzie Chinn,
Economfact: Threats to U.S. Agriculture from U.S. Trade Policies. The Trump Administration initiated a process of
renegotiating the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) with Canada and
Mexico, which includes the option of exiting the deal altogether. In addition,
the United States has started a series of investigations of unfair practices leveled
against China, some of which have already resulted in the imposition of new
tariffs. These trade
policy initiatives threaten agricultural exports both because of the potential
increase of tariffs on exports to Canada and Mexico that would result from a
withdrawal from NAFTA as well as the very real threat of retaliation in
response to other proposed policies.
Susanne Frick,
Andrés Rodríguez-PoseVOX: Urban concentration and economic growth. Urban concentration is typically deemed to lead to
greater national economic growth. This column challenges this view, using an
original dataset covering 68 countries over the past three decades. Urban
concentration levels have decreased or remained stable on average, though these
averages hide widely diverging trends across countries. Although concentration has been beneficial for
high-income countries, this hasn’t been the case for for developing countries.
Tim Harford, The
Undercover Economist: What We Get Wrong About Technology. Blade Runner (1982) is a magnificent film, but
there’s something odd about it. The heroine, Rachael, seems to be a beautiful
young woman. In reality, she’s a piece of technology — an organic robot
designed by the Tyrell Corporation. Los Angeles police detective Rick Deckard
knows; in Rachael, Deckard
is faced with an artificial intelligence so beguiling, he finds himself falling
in love. Yet when he wants to invite Rachael out for a drink, what does he do?
He calls her up from a payphone. There is something revealing about the
contrast between the two technologies — the biotech miracle that is Rachael,
and the graffiti-scrawled videophone that Deckard uses to talk to her. It’s not
simply that Blade Runner fumbled its futurism by failing to anticipate the
smartphone. That’s a forgivable slip, and Blade Runner is hardly the only film
to make it.
Adam Davidson, The
New Yorker: Money, Power, and Deer Urine. How regulators start to serve special
interests. Deer farming doesn’t require
as much acreage as cows or crops, and there’s little need for technology. All
you have to do is throw up some fences, get pregnant does, and buy feed (the
deer like beans and corn). There are roughly ten thousand deer farms in North
America, and some thirty per cent are owned by the Amish. The deer are usually
raised for venison or hunting, but Lapp found another specialty: he is one of
America’s premier producers of deer urine. Lapp, along with the deer-farming
industry as a whole, is facing a crisis in the form of chronic wasting disease,
a plague that attacks white-tailed deer, elk, moose, reindeer, and other
members of the cervid family. The risk-mitigation plan, like all regulation,
isn’t based purely on science; it also takes into account politics and
economics. The plan’s
disparate treatment of urine and meat is an example of what economists call
regulatory capture: the process by which regulators, who are supposed to pursue
solely the public interest, instead become solicitous of the very industries
they regulate.
No comments:
Post a Comment