Olivier
Blanchard, Raghuram Rajan, Kenneth Rogoff , Lawrence H. Summers, MIT Press:
Progress and Confusion. The State of Macroeconomic Policy. What will economic policy look like once the global
financial crisis is finally over? Will it resume the pre-crisis consensus, or
will it be forced to contend with a post-crisis “new normal”? Have we made
progress in addressing these issues, or does confusion remain? In April of
2015, the International Monetary Fund gathered leading economists, both
academics and policymakers, to address the shape of future macroeconomic
policy. This book is the result, with prominent figures—including Ben Bernanke,
Lawrence Summers, and Paul Volcker—offering essays that address topics that
range from the measurement of systemic risk to foreign exchange intervention.
The chapters address whether we have entered a “new normal” of low growth,
negative real rates, and deflationary pressures, with contributors taking
opposing views; whether new financial regulation has stemmed systemic risk; the
effectiveness of macro prudential tools; monetary policy, the choice of inflation
targets, and the responsibilities of central banks; fiscal policy, stimulus,
and debt stabilization; the volatility of capital flows; and the international
monetary and financial system, including the role of international policy
coordination. In light of these discussions, is there progress or confusion
regarding the future of macroeconomic policy? In the final chapter, volume
editor Olivier Blanchard answers: both. Many lessons have been learned; but, as
the chapters of the book reveal, there is no clear agreement on several key
issues.
Martin
Wolf, FT: America’s labour market is not working. In 2014, 12 per cent — close to one in eight — of US
men between the ages of 25 and 54 were neither in work nor looking for it. This
was very close to the Italian ratio and far higher than in other members of the
group of seven leading high-income countries: in the UK, it was 8 per cent; in
Germany and France 7 per cent; and in Japan a mere 4 per cent. In the same
year, the proportion of US prime-age women neither in work nor looking for it
was 26 per cent, much the same as in Japan and less only than Italy’s. US
labour market performance was strikingly poor for the men and women whose
responsibilities should make earning a good income vital. So what is going on.
Kai Rehwald, Michael
Rosholm, Michael Svarer, IZA: Are Public or Private Providers of Employment
Services More Effective? Evidence from a Randomized Experiment. This paper compares the effectiveness of public and
private providers of employment services. Reporting from a randomized field
experiment conducted in Denmark we assess empirically the case for contracting
out employment services for a well-defined group of highly educated job-seekers
(unemployed holding a university degree). Our findings suggest, first, that
private providers deliver more intense, employment-oriented, and earlier
services. Second, public and private provision of employment services are
equally effective regarding subsequent labour market outcomes. And third, the
two competing service delivery systems appear to be equally costly from a
public spending perspective.
Tim
Harford, The Undercover Economist: The real benefits of migration. Among policy wonks and fact-checkers, one statement
in the speech found the spotlight: “The evidence . . . shows that while there
are benefits of selective and controlled immigration, at best the net economic
and fiscal effect of high immigration is close to zero.” (Translation:
immigration costs us nothing but we want to reduce it anyway.) Is May’s summary
of the evidence correct? Probably not, although there is room for reasonable
people to disagree…But there was a far bigger lacuna in May’s speech, and most
commentators have missed it: the fact that these supposed costs or benefits
always omit one crucial group. That group is the migrants themselves. They
prosper hugely from being allowed to migrate yet that prosperity hardly ever
figures in debates about immigration.
Neeraj
Kaushal, Yao Lu, Nicole Denier, Julia Shu-Huah Wang, Stephen J. Trejo,
NBER: Immigrant Employment and Earnings
Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal Data. We study the short-term trajectories of employment,
hours worked, and real wages of immigrants in Canada and the U.S. using
nationally representative longitudinal datasets covering 1996-2008. Models with person fixed effects show that on
average immigrant men in Canada do not experience any relative growth in these
three outcomes compared to men born in Canada. Immigrant men in the U.S., on
the other hand, experience positive annual growth in all three domains relative
to U.S. born men. This difference is largely on account of low-educated immigrant
men, who experience faster or longer periods of relative growth in employment
and wages in the U.S. than in Canada. We
further compare longitudinal and cross-sectional trajectories and find that the
latter over-estimate wage growth of earlier arrivals, presumably reflecting
selective return migration.
Nabanita
Datta Gupta, Mona Larsen, Lars Stage Thomsen, IZA Journal of Labor Policy: Do
wage subsidies for disabled workers reduce their non-employment? - evidence
from the Danish Flexjob scheme. We evaluate the potential of wage subsidy programs for reducing
non-employment of the disabled by exploiting a reform of the Danish Flexjob
scheme targeted towards employing the long-term (partially) disabled. Firms
received a salary reimbursement for all employees granted a Flexjob. We examine
whether a change from full to partial reimbursement to governmental units
affected the share of Flexjobs allocated to retained (insiders) versus
non-employed hirees (outsiders). After the reform, the composition of hires changed
substantially in favor of insiders, both in absolute and relative terms. A
reduction in subsidies thus leads to a decrease in the hiring of the
non-employed disabled.
Yves
Smith, Naked Capitalism: Stunning Rise in Death Rate, Pain Levels for
Middle-Aged, Less Educated Whites. One of the long standing patterns in economies
showing economic growth is longer life spans, and falls are see the result of
severe distress and dislocation, as took place in the period right after the
fall of the Soviet Union, when the expectancies of adult men fell by over seven
years. The US has just become the first country to approach this appalling
record. A stark warning about the level of distress in America comes from an
important study by Angus Deaton, the 2015 Nobel prize winner in economics, and
his wife Anne Case. We’ve embedded their short and readable article at the end
of this post. The authors found that from 1999 to 2013, the death rate among
non-Hispanic whites aged 45 to 54 with a high school education or less rose,
while it fell in other age and ethnic groups. This is an HIV-level silent
epidemic: AIDS killed an estimated 650,000 from the mid-1980s to present, while
an estimated close to half-million died in half that time period who would have
lived had their mortality rates fallen in line with the rest of the population.
It is hard to overstate the significance of these findings.
Mark
Thoma, The Fiscal Times: Are Economists Driven by Ideology or Evidence? The problem is that, in economics, the evidence
rarely delivers clear answers. That leads to ongoing disputes among economists,
and since ideology influences the questions researchers ask, these disputes are
often viewed along ideological lines.Again, so long as, in the end, economists
follow the evidence once it accumulates on one side or the other, I don’t see
this as a problem. But, despite the confidence in the academic community
expressed above, there have been some worrisome trends in recent years. Too
many economists have been unwilling to change their views on issues such as
whether quantitative easing in a deep recession will cause runaway inflation and
interest rate spikes despite clear evidence those views are wrong. That must
change. Our reputation with the public is bad enough as it is, and our best
hope of changing that is to be honest about the evidence, and follow it
wherever it might take us.
No comments:
Post a Comment