Almog Adir, Simon Whitaker, BoE: Do rich countries
lend to poor countries? In the last few years there has been a small net
overall flow of capital from advanced to emerging market economies (EMEs), in
contrast to the ‘paradox’ prevailing for much of this century of capital
flowing the ‘wrong’ way, uphill from poor to rich countries. In this post we show the
‘paradox’ in the aggregate flows actually concealed private capital flowing the
‘right’ way for much of the time. And even during recent turbulence,
foreign direct investment (FDI) flows, likely to be particularly beneficial to
growth, have persisted. But EMEs could still benefit more from
harnessing capital from advanced economies and Argentina has set a useful
precedent as it prepares to take over the Presidency of the G20 in 2018.
Amanda Bayer, David Wilcox, FED: The Unequal
Distribution of Economic Education: A Report on the Race, Ethnicity, and Gender
of Economics Majors at US Colleges and Universities. The distribution of economic education among US
college graduates is quite unequal: female and underrepresented minority
undergraduates, collectively, major in economics at 0.36 the rate that white,
non-Hispanic male students do. This paper makes a four-part contribution to address
this imbalance. First and foremost, we provide detailed comparative data at the institution
level to provoke and inform the attention of economists and senior
administrators at colleges and universities, among others. Second, we establish
a definition of full inclusion in economic education on college and university
campuses and use that definition to evaluate the status quo and to compare
institutions. Third, we illuminate the reasons why the need to improve
the distribution of economic education is urgent, including the imperative to
support economic policymaking. Lastly, we point the way forward, identifying
both currently available resources and reasonable next steps for all involved
parties to take.
Joshua Hyman, AEA: Does Money Matter in the Long Run?
Effects of School Spending on Educational Attainment. This paper measures the effect of increased primary
school spending on students’ college enrollment and completion. Using
student-level panel administrative data, I exploit variation in the school
funding formula imposed by Michigan’s 1994 school finance reform, Proposal A. Students exposed to $1,000 (10
percent) more spending were 3 percentage points (7 percent) more likely to
enroll in college and 2.3 percentage points (11 percent) more likely to earn a
postsecondary degree. The effects were concentrated among districts that
were urban and suburban, lower poverty, and higher achieving at baseline.
Districts targeted the marginal dollar toward schools serving less-poor
populations within the district.
Elizabeth Dhuey, David Figlio, Krzysztof Karbownik,
Jeffrey Roth, NBER: School Starting Age and Cognitive Development. We present evidence of a positive relationship between school starting age
and children’s cognitive development from age 6 to 15 using a regression
discontinuity design and large-scale population-level birth and school data
from the state of Florida. We estimate effects of being relatively old
for grade (being born in September versus August) that are remarkably stable –
always just around 0.2 SD difference in test scores – across a wide range of
heterogeneous groups, based on maternal education, poverty at birth,
race/ethnicity, birth weight, gestational age, and school quality. While the
September-August difference in kindergarten readiness is dramatically different
by subgroup, by the time students take their first exams, the heterogeneity in
estimated effects effectively disappears. We document substantial variation in
compensatory behaviors targeted towards young for grade children. While the
more affluent families tend to redshirt their children, young for grade
children from less affluent families are more likely to be retained in grades
prior to testing. School district practices regarding retention and redshirting
are correlated with improved outcomes for the groups less likely to use those
remediation approaches (i.e., retention in the case of more-affluent families
and redshirting in the case of less-affluent families.) We also study college
and juvenile detention outcomes using administrative data from a large Florida
school district, and show that being an older age at school entry increases children’s college
attainment and reduces the likelihood of being incarcerated for juvenile crime.
Matthew Smith et al: US Treasury Department.
Capitalists in the Twenty-First Century. Have passive rentiers replaced the working rich at the top of the U.S.
income distribution? Using administrative data linking 10 million firms to their
owners, this paper shows that private business owners who actively manage their firms are key for top
income inequality. Private business income accounts for most of the rise of top
incomes since 2000 and the majority of top earners receive private business
income most of which accrues to active owner-managers of mid-market firms in
relatively skill-intensive and unconcentrated industries. Profit falls
substantially after premature owner deaths. Top-owned firms are twice as
profitable per worker as other firms despite similar risk, and rising
profitability without rising scale explains most of their profit growth.
Together, these facts indicate that the working rich remain central to rising
top incomes in the twenty-first century.
Federica Liberini, Andrew J. Oswald, Eugenio Proto,
Michela Redoano, IZA: Was Brexit Caused by the Unhappy and the Old? This paper uses newly released information, from the
Understanding Society data set, to examine the characteristics of individuals
who were for and against Brexit. Two key findings emerge. First, unhappy
feelings contributed to Brexit. However, contrary to commonly heard views, the key channel of influence was
not through general dissatisfaction with life. It was through a person's narrow
feelings about his or her own financial situation. Second, despite some
commentators' guesses, Brexit was not caused by old people. Only the very young
were substantially pro-Remain.
Trenton G. Smith, Steven Stillman, Stuart Craig, IZA:
'Rational Overeating' in a Feast-or-Famine World: Economic Insecurity and the
Obesity Epidemic. Obesity rates
have risen dramatically in the US since the 1980s, but well-identified studies
have struggled to explain the magnitude of the observed changes. In this paper,
we estimate the causal impact of economic insecurity on obesity rates.
Specifically, we construct a synthetic panel of demographic groups over the
period 1988 to 2012 by combining the newly developed Economic Security Index
(ESI) with data from the National Health and Nutrition Examination Surveys
(NHANES). According to our
estimates, increased economic insecurity over this time period explains 50% of
the overall population-level increase in obesity.
Phoebe Weston, Mail: Lefties are good at fast-paced
sports such as tennis and cricket because their technique confuses opponents. Greater the time
pressures in a game, the greater the number of lefties. In sports like cricket and table tennis it was a
great advantage to be left-handed. In slower games like distribution of
left-handers mirrored the general population. Dr Florian Loffing
believes his findings are supported by the 'fighting hypothesis'. This suggests
unfamiliarity gives people an edge in combat.
No comments:
Post a Comment