Larry Summers: Gap
between what is widely believed and market evidence. There is distressingly little evidence in favor of
the proposition that banks that are measured as better capitalized by their
regulators are less likely to fail than other banks. Financial logic embodied
in the celebrated Modigliani Miller theorem and suggested by common sense holds
that substantial reductions in leverage, if achieved, should be associated with
reduced volatility, reduced sensitivity to shocks and lower risk premiums. The data suggest that on a
market value of equity basis, major financial institutions are no less levered
than they were over the period before the crisis.
Dani Rodrik,
Harvard: Is Global Equality the Enemy of National Equality? The bulk of global inequality is accounted for by
income differences across countries rather than within countries. Expanding
trade with China has aggravated inequality in some advanced economies, while
ameliorating global inequality. But the “China shock” is receding and other
low-income countries are unlikely to replicate China’s export-oriented
industrialization experience. Relaxing restrictions on cross-border labor
mobility might have an even stronger positive effect on global inequality.
However it also raises a similar tension. While there would likely be adverse effects on low-skill
workers in the advanced economies, international labor mobility has some
advantages compared to further liberalizing international trade in goods. I
argue that none of the contending perspectives -- national-egalitarian, cosmopolitan,
utilitarian -- provides on its own an adequate frame for evaluating the
consequences.
Peter Dizikes, MIT
News: Darwin visits Wall Street. EMH assumes that individuals always maximize their expected utility —
they find the optimal way to spend and invest, all the time. Lo’s adaptive
markets hypothesis relaxes this dictum on two counts. First, a successful
investing adaptation doesn’t have to be the best of all possible adaptations —
it just has to work fairly well at a given time. Lo’s adaptive markets
hypothesis does not hold that people will constantly be finding the best
possible investments. Instead, as he writes in the book, “consumer behavior is highly
path-dependent,” based on what has worked well in the past. Given those
conditions, the market equivalent of natural selection weeds out poor
investment strategies.
Alberto Alesina,
Bryony Reich, Alessandro Riboni, NBER: Nation-Building, Nationalism and Wars. The increase in army size observed in early modern
times changed the way states conducted wars. Starting in the late 18th century,
states switched from mercenaries to a mass army by conscription. In order for the population to
accept to fight and endure war, the government elites began to provide public
goods, reduced rent extraction and adopted policies to homogenize the
population with nation-building. This paper explores a variety of ways
in which nation-building can be implemented and studies its effects as a
function of technological innovation in warfare.
Markus Gehrsitz,
IZA: Speeding, Punishment, and Recidivism: Evidence from a Regression
Discontinuity Design. This paper
estimates the effects of temporary driver's license suspensions on driving
behavior. A little known rule in the German traffic penalty catalogue maintains
that drivers who commit a series of speeding transgressions within 365 days
should have their license suspended for one month. My regression discontinuity design exploits the
quasi-random assignment of license suspensions caused by the 365-days cut-off
and shows that 1-month license suspensions lower the probability of
recidivating within a year by 20 percent. This is largely a specific
deterrence effect driven by the punishment itself and not by incapacitation,
information asymmetries, or the threat of stiffer future penalties.
No comments:
Post a Comment