Wednesday, February 22, 2017

FEBRUARY 16 2017

Cecchetti, Schoenholtz, Money & Banking: The Future of the Euro. European economic and monetary union (EMU) is not now, nor has it ever been, primarily an economic endeavor. Instead, its founders viewed EMU as a step toward political union in Europe. Helmut Kohl famously elevated the importance of European integration to a question of war and peace in the 21st century. Some (and perhaps many) EMU advocates understood that a common currency would lead to stresses—financial, economic and political. Yet, their experience with the disaster of 20th century European nationalism (and with the policy developments that preceded the euro) led them to expect that these stresses would push future European leaders to make greater sacrifices of sovereignty to save and advance political union. Now, it seems, the public’s will to continue is more uncertain than it has ever been. When asked, the British have voted to leave the European Union. Will the French, when they are given the opportunity in a few months, opt to leave the euro? Will the nationalism that led to repeated 20th century catastrophes resurface? We surely hope not. But markets price risk, not hope.

David Autor, David Dorn, Gordon H. Hanson, Gary Pisano, Pian Shu, NBER: Foreign Competition and Domestic Innovation: Evidence from U.S. Patents. Manufacturing is the locus of U.S. innovation, accounting for more than three quarters of U.S. corporate patents. The rise of import competition from China has represented a major competitive shock to the sector, which in theory could benefit or stifle innovation. In this paper we empirically examine how rising import competition from China has affected U.S. innovation. We confront two empirical challenges in assessing the impact. We map all U.S. utility patents granted by March 2013 to firm-level data using a novel internet-based matching algorithm that corrects for a preponderance of false negatives when using firm names alone. And we contend with the fact that patenting is highly concentrated in certain product categories and that this concentration has been shifting over time. Accounting for secular trends in innovative activities, we find that the impact of the change in import exposure on the change in patents produced is strongly negative. It remains so once we add an extensive set of further industry- and firm-level controls. Rising import exposure also reduces global employment, global sales, and global R&D expenditure at the firm level. It would appear that a simple mechanism in which greater foreign competition induces U.S. manufacturing firms to contract their operations along multiple margins of activity goes a long way toward explaining the response of U.S. innovation to the China trade shock.

Dave Donaldson, Microeconomic Insights: Economic benefits of transportation infrastructure: historical evidence from India and America. Recent research finds that the economic benefits of transportation infrastructure investment can be significant. To measure some of these benefits I analyzed two of the most ambitious transportation projects in history: the building of the vast railroad system in India by the British government from 1870 to 1930 and the dramatic expansion of the railroad network in America from 1870 to 1890. Railroad infrastructure reduced trade costs and increased the shipment of goods. When observing the railroad network in India, I estimated that in a typical district, the arrival of railroad access caused real Gross Domestic Product (GDP) in the agricultural sector (the largest sector of India’s economy at that time) to increase by around 17 percent. My estimates with my colleague, Richard Hornbeck, imply that a counterfactual 1890 U.S. economy without railroads would have seen a 60 percent reduction in the value of aggregate farmland. While these are only two historical case studies, and extrapolating from them to a full understanding of the returns of modern-day investments cannot be done without great care, these lessons from history teach us not to underestimate the economic benefits of transportation infrastructure.

Scott Alexander, Slate Star Codex: Considerations On Cost Disease. My impression is that most people still don’t know about cost disease, or don’t realize the extent of it. So I thought I would make the case for the cost disease in the sectors health care and education – plus a couple more. Per student spending has increased about 2.5x in the past forty years even after adjusting for inflation. At the same time, test scores have stayed relatively stagnant. High school students’ reading scores went from 285 in 1971 to 287 today – a difference of 0.7%. The cost of health care has about quintupled since 1970. It’s actually been rising since earlier than that, but I can’t find a good graph; it looks like it would have been about $1200 in today’s dollars in 1960, for an increase of about 800% in those fifty years. This time I can’t say with 100% certainty that all this extra spending has been for nothing. Life expectancy has gone way up since 1960. We could tell a story like this to explain rising costs in education, health care, etc. If technology increases productivity for skilled laborers in other industries, then less susceptible industries might end up footing the bill since they have to pay their workers more. There’s only one problem: health care and education aren’t paying their workers more; in fact, quite the opposite. What’s happening? I don’t know and I find it really scary.

Tyler Cowen, Bloomberg: Feisty, Protectionist Populism? New Zealand Tried That. What would you think of a Western democratic leader who was populist, obsessed with the balance of trade, especially effective on television, feisty and combative with the press, and able to take over his country’s right-wing party and swing it in a more interventionist direction? Meet Robert Muldoon, prime minister of New Zealand from 1975 to 1984. For all the comparisons of President Donald Trump to Mussolini or various unsavory Latin American leaders, Muldoon is a clearer parallel case. Some of the similarities are striking. Muldoon often made rude or unusually frank comments about foreign leaders (including U.S. President Jimmy Carter and the Australian prime minister), and his diplomats worked hard to undo them. When Muldoon spoke, he so often made the issue about him. His slogan was “New Zealand -- The Way You Want It.” One lesson from the comparison is that a leader like Muldoon can be fairly popular, as he stayed in power from 1975 to 1984, winning three terms despite mistakes, antagonisms and policy failures. He was a plain-speaker who related well to many Kiwi voters, and he was masterful at defusing or rechanneling opposition within his own party.

Andreas Bergh, Milken Institute Review: The Swedish Economy. Triumph of Social Democracy — or Serendipity? By now, the debate regarding the Swedish model had shifted. Chronic economic problems (especially slow productivity growth) were now seen as proof that socialism didn't work – not even in Sweden. A new center-right government was elected in 1991, and this time the mandate was to make fundamental changes in the Swedish model, rather than to polish the one that Sweden had long embraced. In some areas the government succeeded; in others it hit a wall of resistance. Simply put, competition and economic freedom increased in many areas of the Swedish economy. But key areas, notably the labor market and the housing market, remained highly regulated. The winding road Sweden has taken has made it difficult to say whether being more like Sweden involves increasing taxes and government intervention in the economy – or whether it means liberalization, deregulation and welfare-state retrenchment. So, before other countries try too hard to become more like Sweden, it is wise to look back at how Sweden came to be Sweden. The answers may surprise you – they certainly surprise a lot of Swedes.

Robert Frank, NYT: Why Aren’t There More Female Billionaires? Women have been rapidly climbing the employment and wage ladders in recent decades. But only a small fraction have made it to the top rungs — and their progress may be slowing. New research shows that after making big strides in the 1980s and ’90s, the number of women breaking into the top 1 percent of earners has stalled. Women account for only 16 percent of the 1 percent, a number that has remained essentially flat over the past decade, according to a paper by three economists. And they account for only 11 percent of the top 0.1 percent of earners.

Dan Jones, Nature: Cognitive science: Dennett rides again. As Dennett and others argue, genetic evolution is not enough to explain the skills, power and versatility of the human mind. Over the past 10,000 years, human behaviour and our ability to manipulate the planet have changed too quickly for biological evolution to have been the driving force. In Dennett's view, our brains turned into fully fledged modern minds thanks to cultural memes: 'ways of behaving' — pronouncing a word this way, dancing like so — that can be copied, remembered and passed on. Some memes are better than others at getting passed on. This drives natural selection, fashioning memetic design without a designer.

No comments:

Post a Comment