Paul Krugman: What
Have We Learned From The Crisis? The crisis of 2008 and its aftermath have taken place in an environment
in which conservative ideology retains a powerful position in real-world
politics and the academy alike. So relatively few economists or policymakers
have been willing to reconsider their views despite overwhelming empirical
refutation. Or to put it another way, one thing we seem to have learned from the crisis is that
many of our colleagues are less engaged in something like science, an attempt
to understand the world as it is, than we would like to think. Instead, when they
invoke evidence it’s the way a drunkard uses a lamppost: for support, not
illumination. The best excuse one can offer is that even hard scientists
are often reluctant to change their views – “Science progresses one funeral at
a time,” said Max Planck. But what I’m pointing out here isn’t just that too
few economists were willing to learn from the Great Recession, but that there’s
a notable contrast with the way the profession seized on the troubles of the
1970s. This asymmetry is what’s troubling, and suggests that politics and
ideology have distorted our field.
Kenneth Rogoff,
Project Syndicate: Is the Fed Playing Politics? In his recent debate with his opponent Hillary Clinton, Republican
presidential candidate Donald Trump pressed his claim that US Federal Reserve
Chair Janet Yellen is politically motivated. The Fed, Trump claims, is applying overdoses of monetary
stimulus to hypnotize voters into believing that economic recovery is underway.
It’s not a completely crazy idea, but I just don’t see it. If Yellen is
so determined to keep interest rates in a deep freeze, why has she been trying
in recent months to talk up longer-term rates by insisting that the Fed is
likely to hike rates faster than the market currently believes?
Larry Summers, FT:
Men Without Work. Job destruction
caused by technology is not a futuristic concern. It is something we have been living with for
two generations. A simple linear trend
suggests that by
mid-century about a quarter of men between 25 and 54 will not be working at any
moment. I think this is likely a substantial underestimate unless something is
done for a number of reasons.
First everything we hear and see regarding technology suggests the rate
of job destruction will pick up. Think
of the elimination of drivers, and of those who work behind cash
registers. Second, the gains in average
education and health of the workforce over the last 50 years are unlikely to be
repeated. Third, to the extent that
non-work is contagious, it is likely to grow exponentially rather than at a
linear rate. Fourth, declining marriage
rates are likely to raise rates of labor force withdrawal given that non-work
is much more common for unmarried than married men.
Katharine G.
Abraham el al. NBERT: The Consequences of Long Term Unemployment: Evidence from
Matched Employer-Employee Data. It is
well known that the long-term unemployed fare worse in the labor market than
the short-term unemployed, but less clear why this is so. The rich information
on work histories provided by the wage records allows us to control for
individual heterogeneity that could be affecting post-unemployment labor market
outcomes. Even with these controls in place, we find that unemployment duration has a
strongly negative effect on the likelihood of subsequent employment. This
finding is inconsistent with the “bad apple” (heterogeneity) explanation for
why the long-term unemployed fare worse than the short-term unemployed.
We also find that longer unemployment durations are associated with lower
subsequent earnings, though this is mainly attributable to the long-term unemployed
having a lower likelihood of subsequent employment rather than to their having
lower earnings once a job is found.
Ali Alichi, Kory
Kantenga, Juan Solé, IMF: Income Polarization in the United States. Since the turn of the current century, most of
polarization has been towards lower incomes. This result is striking and in
contrast with findings of other recent contributions. In addition, the paper finds
evidence that, after conditioning on income and household characteristics, the marginal
propensity to consume from permanent changes in income has somewhat fallen in
recent years. We assess the potential impacts of these trends on private
consumption. During
1998-2013, the rise in income polarization and lower marginal propensity to
consume have suppressed the level of real consumption at the aggregate level,
by about 3½ percent—equivalent to more than one year of consumption
Bruce Bower,
Science News: Big Viking families nurtured murder. Murder was a calculated family affair among Iceland’s
early Viking settlers. And the bigger the family, the more bloodthirsty. Data
from three family histories spanning six generations support the idea that
disparities in family size have long influenced who killed whom in small-scale
societies. These epic written stories, or sagas, record everything from births
and marriages to deals and feuds. Iceland’s Viking killers had on average of nearly three times as many
biological relatives and in-laws as their victims did, says a team led by
evolutionary psychologist Robin Dunbar of the University of Oxford. Prolific
killers responsible for five or more murders had the greatest advantage in kin
numbers.
No comments:
Post a Comment