Lawrence H.
Summers: The economic consequences of a Trump win would be severe. What I find surprising is that US and global markets
and financial policymakers seem much less sensitive to “Trump risk” than they
are to “Brexit risk”. Options markets suggest only modestly elevated volatility
in the period leading up to the presidential election. While every Fed watcher
comments on the implications of Brexit for the central bank, few, if any,
comment on the possible consequences of a victory for Mr Trump in November.
Yet, as great as the risks of Brexit are to the British economy, I believe the
risks to the US and global economies of Mr Trump’s election as president are
far greater. If he is elected, I would expect a protracted recession to begin
within 18 months. The damage would be felt far beyond the United States.
Chad Syverson,
NBER: Challenges to
Mismeasurement Explanations for the U.S. Productivity Slowdown. Labor productivity in the United States—defined as
total output divided by total hours of labor—has been increasing for over a
century and continues to increase today. However, its growth rate has fallen.
One explanation for this phenomenon focuses on measurement difficulties, in
particular the possibility that current tools for measuring economic growth do
not fully capture recent advances in the goods and services associated with
digital communications technology. Mismeasurement of the prices and quantities
of digital goods and services cannot account for the decline in the growth of
labor productivity.
Torben M. Andersen, Silvia Migali, IZA: Migrant
Workers and the Welfare State. There is
wide concern that migration flows may undermine the financial viability of
generous welfare arrangements. The discussion focuses on welfare arrangements
as attractors of migrants, suggesting that the issue does not pertain to
migrant workers. However, this overlooks how welfare arrangements affect
return-migration in case of social events like job loss. Importantly, migrants
are shown to be self-selected in a way affecting both migration and
return-migration. Two migration regimes prevail. In one, with relatively low
benefits, unemployed workers return, while in the other some stay. Importantly,
the stay or return migration decision is more sensitive to welfare generosity
than the migration decision.
Umut Özek, David
N. Figlio, NBER: Cross-Generational Differences in Educational Outcomes in the
Second Great Wave of Immigration. We make use of a new data source – matched birth records and
longitudinal student records in Florida – to study the degree to which student
outcomes differ across successive immigrant generations. We find evidence
suggesting that early-arriving first generation immigrants perform better than
do second generation immigrants, and second generation immigrants perform
better than third generation immigrants. Among first generation immigrants, the
earlier the arrival, the better the students tend to perform. These patterns of
findings hold for both Asian and Hispanic students, and suggest a general
pattern of successively reduced achievement – beyond a transitional period for
recent immigrants – in the generations following the generation that immigrated
to the United States.
Bjørn Lomborg,
Project Syndicate: The Evidence on Education Reforms. It is almost universally agreed that more education
is good for society. But it turns out that some popular educational policies
achieve very little, while others that are often overlooked can make a huge
difference. Whether for Bangladesh or elsewhere, the real lessons to be taken
away from this research is that we need to look past trendy policies like
adding technology to classrooms. The key to educational progress is to focus on
interventions backed by credible scientific evidence.
Chenkai Wu,
Michelle C Odden, Gwenith G Fisher, Robert S Stawski, JECH: Association of
retirement age with mortality: a population-based longitudinal study among
older adults in the USA. On the basis of
the Health and Retirement Study, 2956 participants who were working at baseline
(1992) and completely retired during the follow-up period from 1992 to 2010
were included. Healthy retirees (n=1934) were defined as individuals who
self-reported health was not an important reason to retire. Over the study
period, 234 healthy and 262 unhealthy retirees died. Among healthy retirees, a
1-year older age at retirement was associated with an 11% lower risk of
all-cause mortality (95% CI 8% to 15%), independent of a wide range of
sociodemographic, lifestyle and health confounders. Similarly, unhealthy
retirees (n=1022) had a lower all-cause mortality risk when retiring later (HR
0.91, 95% CI 0.88 to 0.94). None of the sociodemographic factors were found to
modify the association of retirement age with all-cause mortality.
Efraim Benmelech,
Esteban F. Klor, NBER: What Explains the Flow of Foreign Fighters to ISIS? This paper provides the first systematic analysis of
the link between economic, political, and social conditions and the global phenomenon
of ISIS foreign fighters. We find that poor economic conditions do not drive
participation in ISIS. In contrast, the number of ISIS foreign fighters is
positively correlated with a country's GDP per capita and Human Development
Index (HDI). In fact, many foreign fighters originate from countries with high
levels of economic development, low income inequality, and highly developed
political institutions. Other factors that explain the number of ISIS foreign
fighters are the size of a country's Muslim population and its ethnic
homogeneity. Although we cannot directly determine why people join ISIS, our
results suggest that the flow of foreign fighters to ISIS is driven not by
economic or political conditions but rather by ideology and the difficulty of
assimilation into homogeneous Western countries.
No comments:
Post a Comment