Saleem Bahaj,
Jonathan Bridges, Cian O’Neill, Frederic Malherbe, BoE: Making Macroprudential
Hay When the Sun Shines. It’s not just
what you do; it’s when you do it – many decisions in life have “state
contingent” costs and benefits. The payoffs from haymaking depend crucially
upon the weather. Putting fodder away for a rainy day can be quick, cheap and
prudent when skies are blue. But results may take a soggy and unproductive
turn, if poorly timed. The financial climate is similarly important when
assessing the costs and benefits of macroprudential policy changes. We argue
that it is best to build
the countercyclical capital buffer when the macroeconomic sun is shining. We
find strong empirical evidence to support our claim.
Carola Binder,
Quantitative Ease: The Future is Uncertain, but So Is the Past. In many macroeconomic models, inflation perceptions
should be nearly perfect. After all, inflation statistics are publicly available,
and anyone should be able to access them. The Federal Reserve commissioned the
Michigan Survey of Consumers Research Center to survey consumers about their
perceptions of inflation over the past year and over the past 5- to 10-years,
using analogous wording to the questions about inflation expectations. Surprisingly, consumers seem
just as uncertain about past inflation, or even more so, as about future
inflation.
Lawrence H.
Summers, NYT: It’s Time for a Reset. We need to
redirect the global economic dialogue to the promotion of “responsible
nationalism” rather than on international integration for its own sake.
A classic example of a misguided initiative is the effort to promote a
bilateral investment treaty between the United States and China. Even in the
unlikely event that such a treaty could be negotiated, its effect would be to
trade a reduction in America’s ability to control the behavior of Chinese
companies in the United States for increased security for American global
companies when they locate production facilities or otherwise invest in China.
From the point of view of a typical middle-class American voter, the deal is
lose-lose.
David Autor et
al., NBER: Foreign Competition and Domestic Innovation: Evidence from U.S.
Patents. In this paper we empirically
examine how rising import competition from China has affected U.S. innovation.
We confront two empirical challenges in assessing the impact. We map all U.S.
utility patents granted by March 2013 to firm-level data using a novel
internet-based matching algorithm that corrects for a preponderance of false
negatives when using firm names alone. And we contend with the fact that
patenting is highly concentrated in certain product categories and that this
concentration has been shifting over time. Accounting for secular trends in
innovative activities, we find that the impact of the change in import exposure on the change in
patents produced is strongly negative. It remains so once we add an
extensive set of further industry- and firm-level controls. Rising import
exposure also reduces global employment, global sales, and global R&D
expenditure at the firm level. It would appear that a simple mechanism in which
greater foreign competition induces U.S. manufacturing firms to contract their
operations along multiple margins of activity goes a long way toward explaining
the response of U.S. innovation to the China trade shock.
Eduardo Porter,
NYT: A Dilemma for Humanity: Stark Inequality or Total War. Mr. Obama has led the most progressive administration
since Lyndon B. Johnson’s half a century ago, raising taxes on the rich to
expand the safety net for the less fortunate. Still, by the White House’s own
account, eight years of trench warfare in Washington trimmed the top
1-percenters’ share, after taxes and transfers, to only 15.4 percent, from 16.6
percent of the nation’s income. So what does this leave us with? Another world
war, with or without thermonuclear weapons? Let’s hope not. State collapse
looks highly unlikely outside of some bits of sub-Saharan Africa. Revolution?
Little chance, given the absence of any powerful ideological challenge to
capitalism. “The world of
the future is likely to be quite stable and have very high inequality,” Mr.
Scheidel told me. Maybe we should just learn to stop worrying and love it.
David Card, Ana
Rute Cardoso, Patrick Kline, Microeconomic insights: The gender wage gap: how
firms influence women’s pay relative to men. Employers’ pay policies can contribute to the gender wage gap if women
are less likely to work at high-paying firms or if women negotiate worse wage
bargains then men. Analysing data from Portugal’s labour market, this research
finds that differences
among firms can explain up to 20% of the gender wage gap. Women tend to be
employed at less productive firms that offer lower wages to their employees.
Moreover, when women are hired by better-paying firms, their wages rise less
than men, possibly because they are less effective negotiators. These findings
call for renewed attention to equal pay and fair hiring laws.
Deborah M. Gordon,
OECD: Ants, algorithms and complexity without management. The process that generates simple interactions from
colony behavior is what computer scientists call a distributed algorithm. No
single unit, such as an ant or a router in a data network, knows what all the
others are doing and tells them what to do. Instead, interactions between each
unit and its local connections add up to the desired outcome. The
correspondences between the regulation of collective behaviour and the changing
conditions in which it operates might provide insight, and even inspire
thinking about policy, in human social systems.
For ants or
neurons, the network has no content. Studying natural systems can show us how
the rhythm of local interactions creates patterns in the behaviour and
development of large groups, and how such feedback evolves in response to a
changing world.
Joel Mokyr,
Project Syndicate: Is Our Economic Future Behind Us? In fact, pessimism has reigned over economists’
outlooks for centuries. In 1830, the British Whig historian Thomas Macaulay
observed that, “[i]n every age, everybody knows that up to his own time,
progressive improvement has been taking place; nobody seems to reckon on any
improvement in the next generation.” Why, he asked, do people expect “nothing
but deterioration”? Soon, Macaulay’s perspective was vindicated by the dawn of
the railway age. Transformative advances in steel, chemicals, electricity, and
engineering soon followed. When
it comes to our technological future, I would expect a similar outcome. Indeed,
I would go so far as to say, “We ain’t seen nothin’ yet.” Technological
advances will create a tailwind of hurricane-like proportions to the world’s
most advanced economies.
Robert J. Shiller,
Economic View: Trump, and Great Business Ideas for America. A businessman with a lifetime of experience in
management has been elected president of the United States. Donald J. Trump’s
administration may be viewed as an experiment — an opportunity to discover
whether one particular businessman’s perspective and skills will be assets in
governing a nation. A
business-oriented president could be helpful in this intellectual world, too,
by taking actions like doubling the budget for the National Science Foundation,
which was created in 1950 when Harry S. Truman was president, and infusing the
National Institutes of Health, the National Endowment for the Arts and the
National Endowment for the Humanities with more cash. In the best of
outcomes, Mr. Trump will find a way to live up to this opportunity in the
coming years, carefully fulfilling a promise to bring in the “best and most
serious people” in the business community rather than the most loyal.
Eduardo Porter,
NYT: Earth Isn’t Doomed Yet. The Climate Could Survive Trump Policies. It’s certainly possible that a Trump administration
will drop the Clean Power Plan and renege on the Paris accord. But as long as it keeps the
nation’s nuclear power plants online, continues tax incentives for wind and
solar energy and stays out of the way of the shale energy revolution, the U.S.
might outperform the commitments that the Obama administration made in Paris.
For all his promises to bring back coal jobs in Appalachia, Mr. Trump might be
drawn in a different direction by his own objectives of promoting natural gas
and achieving energy independence. If he gives those goals high priority, he
could well end up pursuing policies that would ultimately lower carbon
emissions.
Justin Fox,
Bloomberg: From Peak Oil to Peak Oil Demand in Just Nine Years. Simon Henry, the chief financial officer of Royal
Dutch Shell, recently predicted a demand peak "between five and 15 years
hence.” And as Bloomberg's Javier Blas and Laura Blewitt pointed out last week,
even the IEA thinks that demand from passenger cars, long the biggest users of
oil, has already peaked. So that's pretty exciting! The peaking of oil demand would mark a major
historic turning point.
Ted Nordhaus, Jessica Lovering, The Breakthrogh: Does
Climate Policy Matter? The results as
elaborated below have been decidedly mixed. For the most part, emissions signals from climate
policies have consistently been overwhelmed by exogenous macro-economic and technological
developments. The impact of climate policies has proven difficult to
disentangle from other emissions drivers such as population growth, economic
expansions and recessions, the collapse of the former Soviet Union, German
reunification, the shale revolution in the United States and the shuttering of
large nuclear fleets in Japan and Germany, to name just a few prominent factors
and examples.
Nouriel Roubini,
Project Syndicate: The Taming of Trump. But it is actually more likely that Trump will pursue pragmatic,
centrist policies. For starters, Trump is a businessman who relishes the “art
of the deal,” so he is by definition more of a pragmatist than a blinkered
ideologue. His choice to run as a populist was tactical, and does not
necessarily reflect deep-seated beliefs. Indeed, Trump is a wealthy real-estate
mogul who has lived his entire life among other rich businessmen. He is a savvy
marketer who tapped into the political zeitgeist by pandering to working-class
Republicans and “Reagan Democrats,” some of whom may have supported Vermont
Senator Bernie Sanders in the Democratic primary. This allowed him to stand out
in a crowded field of traditional pro-business, pro-Wall Street, and
pro-globalization politicians. Once in office, Trump will throw symbolic red meat to his supporters
while reverting to the traditional supply-side, trickle-down economic policies
that Republicans have favored for decades.
Andrew Prokop,
VOX: Will economic populism lead Democrats to victory? Senate results should make us skeptical. Interestingly
enough, in two of those
crucial Midwestern states that flipped to Trump, Democratic Senate candidates
campaigned on economically populist platforms — but they did notably worse than
Hillary Clinton. Russ Feingold underperformed Clinton by 2.4 points in
Wisconsin, and Ted Strickland underperformed her by 12.8 points in Ohio. Feingold
amassed a populist record of challenging big money and special interests when
he was in the Senate, and Strickland harshly condemned trade deals during his
campaign against Rob Portman (who served as George W. Bush’s US trade
representative).
Kenneth M. Langa,
JAMA: A Comparison of the Prevalence of Dementia in the United States in 2000
and 2012. The aging of the US
population is expected to lead to a large increase in the number of adults with
dementia, but some recent studies in the United States and other high-income
countries suggest that the age-specific risk of dementia may have declined over
the past 25 years. We used data from the Health and Retirement Study (HRS), a
nationally representative, population-based longitudinal survey of individuals
in the United States 65 years or older from the 2000. The prevalence of dementia in the United States
declined significantly between 2000 and 2012. An increase in educational
attainment was associated with some of the decline in dementia prevalence, but
the full set of social, behavioral, and medical factors contributing to the
decline is still uncertain.
Jessi Hempel,
Backchannel: According to Snopes, Fake News Is Not the Problem. But as managing editor of the fact-checking site
Snopes, Brooke Binkowski believes Facebook’s perpetuation of phony news is not
to blame for our epidemic of misinformation. “It’s not social media that’s the
problem,” she says emphatically. The misinformation crisis, according to
Binkowski, stems from something more pernicious. In the past, the sources of accurate information were
recognizable enough that phony news was relatively easy for a discerning reader
to identify and discredit. The problem, Binkowski believes, is that the public
has lost faith in the media broadly.
International
Number Ones. Every country is the best at something: Even if it’s a bad thing, like murder, child
marriages or spam email. The aptly-named Information is Beautiful website has
sifted through piles of data from the UN, the CIA, the Guardian and a bunch of
other places to compile a
world map that awards a gold star to just about every country on the planet.
Patrick Schneider,
BoE: There are two productivity puzzles. Much has been written about the productivity puzzle. But there are actually two
puzzles apparent in the data – one in the level that hit at the crisis and the
other in the growth rate, which is a more recent phenomenon – and they could be
driven by completely different sources. Distinguishing between the two
puzzles is important precisely because of these potential differences – if
anyone analyses the puzzle as a whole looking for the force driving it, the
actual underlying variety will confound our estimates of the relative
importance of these drivers.
Thomas Piketty,
The Guardian: We must rethink globalization, or Trumpism will prevail. Let it be said at once: Trump’s victory is primarily due to the explosion in
economic and geographic inequality in the United States over several decades
and the inability of successive governments to deal with this. It is
time to change the political discourse on globalization: trade is a good thing,
but fair and sustainable development also demands public services,
infrastructure, health and education systems. In turn, these themselves demand
fair taxation systems. If we fail to deliver these, Trumpism will prevail.
Simen Markussen, Knut Røed, IZA: Leaving Poverty
Behind? The Effects of Generous Income Support Paired with Activation. We evaluate a comprehensive activation program in
Norway targeted at hard-to-employ social assistance claimants with reduced work
capacity. The program offers a combination of tailored rehabilitation, training
and job practice, and a generous, stable, and non-meanstested benefit. Its main
aims are to mitigate poverty and subsequently promote selfsupporting employment.
Our evaluation strategy exploits a geographically staggered program introduction,
and the causal effects are
identified on the basis of changes in employment prospects that coincide with
local program implementation in a way that correlates with the predicted
probability of becoming a participant. We find that the program raised
employment prospects considerably.
David M. Cutler,
Wei Huang, Adriana Lleras-Muney, NBER: Economic Conditions and Mortality:
Evidence from 200 Years of Data. Using data covering over 100 birth-cohorts in 32 countries, we examine
the short- and long-term effects of economic conditions on mortality. We find that small, but not
large, booms increase contemporary mortality. Yet booms from birth to age 25,
particularly those during adolescence, lower adult mortality. A simple
model can rationalize these findings if economic conditions differentially
affect the level and trajectory of both good and bad inputs into health.
Indeed, air pollution and alcohol consumption increase in booms. In contrast,
booms in adolescence raise adult incomes and improve social relations and
mental health, suggesting these mechanisms dominate in the long run.
Justin R. Pierce
and Peter K. Schott, FED: Trade Liberalization and Mortality: Evidence from
U.S. Counties. We investigate
the impact of a large economic shock on mortality. We find that counties more exposed to a
plausibly exogenous trade liberalization exhibit higher rates of suicide and
related causes of death, concentrated among whites, especially white males.
These trends are consistent with our finding that more-exposed counties
experience relative declines in manufacturing employment, a sector in which
whites and males are disproportionately employed. We also examine other causes
of death that might be related to labor market disruption and find both positive
and negative relationships. More-exposed counties, for example, exhibit lower
rates of fatal heart attacks.
Christopher
Chabris, WSJ: Does Chess Make You Smarter? To test the independent effect of playing chess, the Educational
Endowment Foundation in the United Kingdom sponsored an experiment last year in
which fifth-grade classrooms in 100 schools were randomly chosen either to
incorporate chess lessons into their regular schedule or to continue
instruction as usual. The
students weren’t given IQ tests at the end of the year, but their performance
in math, science and reading was evaluated. Those who had studied chess did no
better than those who had not. A similar but slightly less rigorous 2011
study in Italy found, however, that adding chess instruction to third-grade
classrooms improved the performance of students on math tests.
Lynn Vavreck, NYT:
This Election Was Not About the Issues. Blame the Candidates. I compared the content of campaign ads with the
content of news articles about two specific topics: candidate traits or
characteristics, and the economy or jobs. Both the candidates and news organizations spent more
time discussing the candidates’ fitness for office (or lack of it) than they
did the nation’s economy. And the imbalance grew more lopsided as the election
approached. Using analytic tools provided by Crimson Hexagon, I
categorized the campaign news coverage of 23 media outlets. This consisted of
four broadcast networks; three cable news networks; National Public Radio and
Hugh Hewitt on the radio; two online news sites; and 12 newspapers. I
specifically searched for news about Mrs. Clinton’s campaign and her email
server or her campaign and WikiLeaks, and several controversies connected to
Mr. Trump’s campaign. From this point, 53 percent of the campaign articles
mentioning either controversies or the economy discuss Mrs. Clinton’s email,
while only 6 percent mention her alongside jobs or the economy. As for Mr.
Trump, 31 percent mention his entanglements, while 10 percent mention him
related to jobs and the economy.
Lawrence H.
Summers, Summers Blog: A badly designed US stimulus will only hurt the working
class. Populist
economics will play out differently in the US than in emerging markets. But the
results will be no better. All with a stake in the global economy must
hope that now, as has happened often in the past, a US president faced with the
responsibility of governing preserves the valid core of campaign economic plans
while making major adjustments. Not even US presidents with political mandates can
repeal the laws of economics.
Olivier Blanchard,
PIIE: In Light of the Elections: Recession, Expansion, and Inequality. So, in the end, expansion or recession will depend
on the balance between macroeconomic and trade measures. My own guess is the
first will dominate, and growth will be sustained, at least for some time. Will
it be enough to satisfy those who voted for Donald Trump, worried about their
incomes and their futures? I am not so sure. Growth will indeed lift most
boats. But many measures will push in the opposite direction. Lower corporate
taxes, lower personal taxes on the rich, and financial deregulation will
increase the share of output going to capital (this probably explains in part
what is happening to the stock market). Tariffs on foreign goods may save some middle class jobs
but will destroy others and increase the cost of living for those at the bottom
end of the income distribution. Inequality may well go up, not down
Zidong An, IMF:The
Evidence that Growth Creates Jobs: A New Look at an Old Relationship. New research from the IMF looks at Okun’s Law and
asks, based on the evidence, will growth create jobs? The findings show a striking variation across
countries in how employment responds to GDP growth over the course of a year.
In some countries, when growth picks up, employment goes up and unemployment
falls; in other countries the response is quite muted. A pick-up in
growth—through a stimulus to the demand side of the economy, for instance
increased government spending on infrastructure—will result in more jobs.
Heather Hurlburt,
Project Syndicate:The Myth of the Women’s Vote. It may seem surprising that only 54% of the female electorate voted for
Hillary Clinton, the first woman nominated for president by a major party. But while gender is a strong
marker for how Americans think about certain issues, it is not the best
predictor of how they will vote. It turns out that female candidates do
not face a single gender gap, but rather multiple gender gaps.
Stumbling and
Mumbling Blog: Is globalization to blame? Donald Trump’s victory is being seen as a backlash against
globalization. For me, this poses the question: to what extent is globalization
to blame for the decline in many workers’ real incomes? The answer, I suspect,
is: not much. These papers by Ann Harrison and colleagues and Jonathan Haskel
and colleagues show that it
is very hard to link declining US real wages to increased openness to trade.
Equally, it is unproven (to say the least) whether increased immigration has
contributed to falling wages: George Borjas’s claim that it is has has been
sharply challenged.
Binyamin
Appelbaum, NYT: A Little-Noticed Fact About Trade: It’s No Longer Rising. The growth of trade among nations is among the most
consequential and controversial economic developments of recent decades. Yet despite the noisy debates,
which have reached new heights during this presidential campaign, it is a
little-noticed fact that trade is no longer rising. The volume of global
trade was flat in the first quarter of 2016, then fell by 0.8 percent in the
second quarter, according to statisticians in the Netherlands, which happens to
keep the best data.
Arthur Turrell,
BoE: Power and progress. Energy is the
fundamental currency of the physical world, while GDP is the imperfect
catch-all measure of economic progress. Across countries, electricity and GDP
are very strongly correlated. But which way does the causality go? Studies have
found evidence for GDP causing electricity generation, electricity generation
causing GDP and for a bi-directional relationship. For the UK, the evidence suggests that it is
a bi-directional dependence, based on a bootstrapped Granger causality test. Given over 85% of the world’s
primary energy consumption comes from fossil fuels, countries around the world
are either going to have to find new ways to produce power or break the link
between GDP and electricity – whichever direction the causality runs.
Tim Gohmann,
behavioraleconomics.com: How Donald Trump Won the Election: A Behavioral
Economics Explanation. Trump’s campaign execution was a
simple yet elegant display of behavioral economics in practice as follows:
1. IDENTIFICATION — make such disparaging remarks about minorities that the
core target “see themselves” in the candidate; 2. UTILITY — communicate the
most motivating expected campaign result to the core target — a restoration of
the value of their labor (and financial status), the cornerstone to making
America great again; and 3. LOSS AVERSION — motivate the core target by
suggesting that this was their only chance to recover their social and
financial status, thereby empowering them to turn out in such record numbers
that the opposition was overwhelmed.
Paul Krugman, NYT:
The Economic Fallout. It really does
now look like President Trump, and markets are plunging. When might we expect
them to recover? Frankly, I find it hard to care much, even though this is my
specialty. The disaster for America and the world has so many aspects that the
economic ramifications are way down my list of things to fear. Still, I guess
people want an answer: if the question is when markets will recover, a
first-pass answer is never.
Lawrence H. Summers,
Harvard University: Voters sour on traditional economic policy. It can hardly come as a great surprise that when
economic growth falls short year after year and when its beneficiaries are a
small subset of the population, electorates turn surly. They lose confidence in
traditional policy approaches and their advocates. Looking back at the
political traumas of 1968 when there were people in the streets in many
countries, it is clear that there was something going on beyond specific issues
like Vietnam in the US. In
the same way as with Brexit, the rise of Donald Trump and Bernie Sanders, the
strength of rightwing nationalists in many European countries, Vladimir Putin’s
strength in Russia and the return of Mao worship in China, it is hard to escape
the conclusion that the world is seeing a renaissance of populist
authoritarianism. It is hard to escape the conclusion that the world is
seeing a renaissance of populist authoritarianism.
José Cuesta, Mario
Negre, Christoph Lakner, VOX: Know your facts: Poverty numbers. The percentage of people living in extreme poverty
around the world has fallen by more than half over the past three decades. But polls show that most people are
not only ignorant of this fact, but believe that poverty has increased.
This column explores progress towards ending global poverty by 2030, the first
of the UN’s Sustainable Development Goals. Poverty figures have fallen around
the world since 1990, and there is a broad consensus on the policies needed for
further reductions. Eradicating global poverty is achievable, but it is
dependent on global and domestic political cooperation.
Nancy Cartwright,
Angus Deaton, VOX: The limitations of randomised controlled trials. In recent years, the use of randomised controlled
trials has spread from labour market and welfare programme evaluation to other
areas of economics, and to other social sciences, perhaps most prominently in
development and health economics. This column argues that some of the popularity of such trials rests
on misunderstandings about what they are capable of accomplishing, and
cautions against simple extrapolations from trials to other contexts.
The National
Infrastructure Commission, UK: Call for Evidence. The Commission is a permanent body that “will operate
independently, at arm’s length from government, as an executive agency of HM
Treasury”. NIC has been
established to provide the government with impartial, expert advice on major
long-term infrastructure challenges. The Commission is launching a 15 week call
for evidence to provide input into the development of its National
Infrastructure Assessment. The Commission has identified 28 key
questions which it believes will be important to answer in order to understand the
main infrastructure challenges facing the country over the coming decades.
Patrick Bennett,
Amine Ouazad, VOX: The relationship between job displacement and crime. A substantial body of literature finds significant
effects of unemployment rates on crime rates. However, relatively little is
known about the direct impact of individual unemployment on individual crime.
This column examines the effect of job displacement on crime using 15 years of
Danish administrative data. Being
subject to a sudden and unexpected mass-layoff is found to increase the
probability that an individual commits a crime. However, the findings
stress the importance of policies targeting education and income inequality in
mitigating crime.
Ángel Ubide, VOX: The case for an active fiscal policy. The pre-crisis consensus was, and remains, very
strong – the business cycle would be managed by monetary policy, while fiscal
policy would focus solely on debt sustainability. In a world of zero interest rates, however, fiscal policy
has to contribute to supporting aggregate demand and protecting against
deflationary risks. This column outlines three ways in which a
well-designed expansionary fiscal policy stance can contribute to better
economic outcomes.
Stephen Redding,
David Weinstein, VOX: What big data tells us about real income growth. Big data stands to transform economic measurement in
substantial ways. The volume and precision of data available allows economists
to revisit the foundational assumptions underpinning common indexes. This
column presents a new empirical methodology that leverages big data to
translate nominal numbers into real output or welfare. ‘The unified approach’
nests major price indexes and addresses implicit biases in these measures. An examination with barcode data
suggests that standard methods of measuring welfare overstate cost of living
increases by ignoring new products and demand shifts.
Melanie Arntz,
Terry Gregory, Ulrich Zierahn, OECD: The Risk of Automation for Jobs in OECD
Countries. A Comparative Analysis. In recent years, there has been a revival of concerns that automation
and digitalisation might after all result in a jobless future. These studies
follow an occupation-based approach proposed by Frey and Osborne (2013), i.e.
they assume that whole occupations rather than single job-tasks are automated
by technology. We estimate the job automatibility of jobs for 21 OECD countries
based on a task-based approach. In contrast to other studies, we take into
account the heterogeneity of workers’ tasks within occupations. Overall, we find that, on average
across the 21 OECD countries, 9 % of jobs are automatable. The threat from
technological advances thus seems much less pronounced compared to the
occupation-based approach. We further find heterogeneities across OECD
countries. For instance, while the share of automatable jobs is 6 % in Korea,
the corresponding share is 12 % in Austria. Differences between countries may
reflect general differences in workplace organisation, differences in previous
investments into automation technologies as well as differences in the
education of workers across countries.
OECD Statistics
Directorate: Statistical Insights: What does GDP per capita tell us about
households’ material well-being? The preferred
measure of people’s material well-being is household disposable income per
capita, which represents the maximum amount a household can consume without
having to reduce its assets or to increase its liabilities. The above-mentioned
factors can create
significant differences between measures of household disposable income per
capita and GDP per capita. The United States for example see its position
relative to the OECD average jump by more than 10 percentage points. On the
other hand, Norway falls from 1st on a GDP basis to 4th on a household
disposable income basis while Ireland drops dramatically. Switzerland also sees
falls in its household income vs GDP ranking, partly because of the relatively
large number of cross-border workers.
Manudeep Bhuller,
Gordon B. Dahl, Katrine V. Løken, Magne Mogstad, University of
Chicago: Incarceration, Recidivism and Employment. We construct a panel dataset containing the criminal
behavior and labor market outcomes of the entire population, and exploit the
random assignment of criminal cases to judges who differ systematically in
their stringency in sentencing defendants to prison. Using judge stringency as
an instrumental variable, we
find that imprisonment discourages further criminal behavior, and that the
reduction extends beyond incapacitation. Incarceration decreases the
probability an individual will reoffend within 5 years by 27 percentage points,
and reduces the number of offenses over this same period by 10 criminal
charges. In comparison, OLS shows positive associations between
incarceration and subsequent criminal behavior. This sharp contrast suggests
the high rates of recidivism among ex-convicts is due to selection, and not a
consequence of the experience of being in prison. Exploring factors that may
explain the preventive effect of incarceration, we find the decline in crime is
driven by individuals who were not working prior to incarceration. Contrary to
the widely embraced ‘nothing works’ doctrine, these findings demonstrate that time
spent in prison with a focus on rehabilitation can indeed be preventive.
Robert J. Shiller, Times: What’s Behind a Rise in Ethnic Nationalism?
Maybe the Economy. It is natural to ask whether something so broad might
have a common cause, other than the obvious circumstantial causes like the
gradual fading of memories about the horrors of ethnic conflict in World War II
or the rise in this century of forms of violent ethnic terrorism. Economics is my specialty, and I
think economic factors may explain at least part of the trend.
Pascal
Mittermaier, Project Syndicate: How Trees Make Cities Healthier. Heat waves account for more deaths than any other
type of weather-related event, killing more than 12,000 people worldwide each
year. Making matters worse, cities tend to have higher rates of air pollution,
especially fine particulate matter (PM) resulting from the combustion of fossil
fuels and biomass, which contributes to up to three million deaths every year. Fortunately, there is a simple
step that municipal leaders can take to reduce both extreme heat and air
pollution: plant more trees.